New Zealand’s Left vs. the Fiscal Straitjacket
Why the Left struggles to deliver real change in New Zealand—trapped by a tax system that protects income.
One of the most interesting things about politics for me is how often people assume they’re backing a progressive policy—when in reality, they’re reinforcing right-wing frameworks. Or when people think that only right-wing parties are neoliberal, when in fact New Zealand operates in a neoliberal governing framework, so all parties operate within a neoliberal sandbox.
I’ve lost count of the times someone has passionately defended a policy as left-wing, only for me to say, "Actually, that’s a right-leaning idea." The look of surprise is always satisfying—not because I’m trying to score points, but because it means they’re starting to question their own political certainty, which in my mind is a positive step towards a less polarized society.
And that’s the thing: political certainty is comfortable, but problematic and deceptive. We like to believe our policies fit neatly into Left and Right categories, and that our behaviors and are also consistent with Left and Right values, but we are all a walking political contradiction that I wish we were more aware off.
This article isn’t about moral judgments—the Left isn’t inherently good; the Right isn’t inherently bad. It’s about recognizing how some of the most widely accepted progressive policies in New Zealand actually operate within right-wing economic constraints. From means-testing to homeownership schemes, from community-led initiatives to our tax system, the policies we assume will reduce inequality often reinforce the very structures that sustain it.
If the Left wants to deliver real change, it needs to break free from this fiscal straitjacket. But first, we need to see it for what it is.
1. The Means-Testing Trap
One of the most pervasive assumptions in progressive circles is that support should be targeted at those who "need it most." It sounds logical—direct resources to the most vulnerable, ensure maximum impact, and avoid wasteful spending on those who don't require assistance. But what if this approach, rather than being a hallmark of progressive policy, is actually reinforcing a right-wing economic framework?
Means-testing is, at its core, a neoliberal tool. It assumes that state support should be minimized, distributed selectively, and justified through individual economic circumstances rather than universal entitlement. While the intention may be to help those in need, the effect is often exclusionary, punitive, and administratively complex, reinforcing divisions between the "deserving" and "undeserving" poor while entrenching economic insecurity.
Take Working for Families, one of New Zealand’s most significant income support policies. It was designed to help low- and middle-income families, but because it’s means-tested, it creates harsh cutoffs and unintended consequences. If a young person in a family on this scheme starts working over 30 hours per week at age 16+, their family can suddenly lose crucial entitlements—not because they’re suddenly wealthy, but because they’ve crossed an arbitrary threshold. Many families aren't even aware of this rule until they experience the financial shock firsthand.
Similarly, the Student Allowance is means-tested based on parental income until the age of 24. This assumes that parents are financially supporting their adult children well into their mid-20s—an assumption that ignores the realities of many working-class and middle-income families. The result is that many students are forced to take on debt while others, often from wealthier backgrounds, continue to receive financial support from their families without needing state assistance.
Contrast this with New Zealand Superannuation, one of the few truly universal welfare policies in the country, which I’m not sure will last for too much longer. Regardless of income, every citizen over 65 receives a pension. There’s no stigma, no bureaucratic hurdles, and no perverse incentives to avoid earning more. It’s one of the most popular and politically untouchable welfare policies in the country. Yet, when it comes to younger people—families, students, and workers—the government applies a different logic: instead of providing universal support, they force people to jump through bureaucratic hoops to prove their need.
This isn’t an accident. Neoliberal ideology thrives on conditionality—it reinforces the idea that state support is an exception rather than a right. It also undermines solidarity. Universal programs create a broad base of support across society (think of public healthcare or superannuation), whereas means-tested programs pit different groups against each other, encouraging resentment between those who qualify and those who don’t.
Means-testing also contributes to policy churn and instability. When Labour is in power, thresholds might be adjusted to be more generous; when National takes over, they tighten eligibility criteria. The result is a politicized welfare system that fluctuates with each electoral cycle, leaving vulnerable people in a constant state of uncertainty.
If the Left wants to break free from the neoliberal sandbox, it must move beyond means-testing to more universalism. But with our current tax farmwork that is unreasonable, and we just can’t afford it. The reason public healthcare and superannuation are so politically resilient is precisely because they’re universal. Imagine if student support, family income support, or even rental assistance were treated the same way—available to all, without punitive cutoffs or endless paperwork. Great, but we all need to p ay more tax, from income to another type of tax like capital gains or land tax.
The question isn’t whether we should help those in need. It’s can we afford to with our tax system. Until then we will keep having to choose between making support conditional for some groups or paying more for universality for everybody. Because as it stands, our status quo, it creates and will keep creating more inequality than it solves.
2. The Homeownership Myth
"Everyone should be able to own their own home" is a statement few would disagree with. During my many conversations about how to strengthen social cohesion, I hear over and over again, '“well everybody owning a home would be a good start”. It's a noble aspiration that speaks to our desires for security, fairness and autonomy. But this deeply market-oriented framework has somehow become coded as progressive in New Zealand politics. It’s not.
Let's examine this paradox. Both Labour and National champion policies to get first-time buyers "on the property ladder" – KiwiBuild, First Home Grants, low-deposit schemes. These are fundamentally market-based solutions: they aim to help people participate in the private property market rather than questioning the market's role in housing provision. Yet they're often celebrated as progressive victories for housing justice.
This political coding is remarkable. Consider KiwiBuild: it was branded as a progressive solution to housing inequality, but its core mechanism was turning the government into a property developer, building homes to sell at market rates to qualified buyers. When it failed to meet its targets, the debate focused on delivery numbers rather than questioning whether market mechanisms can solve market failures.
What's particularly interesting is how these framing shapes our policy imagination. By accepting homeownership as the primary path to housing security, we've naturally oriented toward market-based solutions. This isn't inherently wrong – markets can be efficient allocation mechanisms. But we've come to see market participation as a progressive outcome, while also blaming the market for our problems.
The reality is complex. Any significant change to housing provision in New Zealand would require fundamental shifts in our tax system and public spending priorities. The Vienna model that housing advocates often cite relies on high income taxes, land value capture, and a centuries-old approach to public land banking that would be challenging to replicate in our post-colonial context. And that’s not counting the tiny issue of New Zealand being a post-colonial country which comes with its own legacy of issues.
This gets to the heart of our political confusion. We've mislabeled market-based housing policies as progressive when they're actually classic right-wing approaches: they prioritize individual property ownership, rely on market mechanisms (government led or private developers led), it’s the same, and treat housing as an asset class. This doesn't make them wrong – but it does make them interesting examples of how political labels can mask policy fundamentals.
When house prices rise, we celebrate this as economic good news while simultaneously lamenting housing inequality. This contradiction exists because we're trying to solve housing affordability through mechanisms that fundamentally depend on housing remaining a profitable asset class.
The key insight isn't that market-based solutions are wrong or that state intervention is right. It's that we should be more precise about the ideological foundations of our policies. Helping people buy homes through market mechanisms isn't progressive policy wearing market clothing – it's market policy wearing progressive clothing.
This clarity matters because it helps us understand policy trade-offs better. If we want to treat housing primarily as a right rather than an asset, we need to acknowledge this would require significantly higher taxation and state intervention. If we prefer market mechanisms, we should acknowledge these will naturally favor those with capital and create unequal outcomes.
There's no easy answer. But there is value in understanding that when we promote homeownership as the solution to housing inequality, we're not actually challenging market frameworks – we're reinforcing them. Whether that's good or bad depends on your political philosophy. What's important is being clear about which framework we're actually operating within.
3. The Community Responsibility Paradox: Self-Determination or State Abdication?
How many times have we heard the Left say: "We know our community best”, "We can do this better than any government department." Well, yes but that is a Right-wing approach, so if you are for this, you might be less Left and Righter than you think.
This is another political paradox: community-led initiatives being celebrated as progressive while actually implementing a fundamentally right-wing framework of state devolution.
Consider how this plays out in Aotearoa. When communities – particularly Māori and Pacific communities – step up to feed their people during crises, we celebrate their manaakitanga and community spirit. And rightly so. But we rarely question why food security has become a community responsibility rather than a systematic state one.
The Oranga Tamariki partnerships with iwi provide an example of this dynamic. On one level, these partnerships represent progress toward tino rangatiratanga and recognizing iwi authority over the wellbeing of their tamariki. But examine the funding and accountability structures, and you'll find something more complex: iwi are often expected to deliver state-level services with community-level resources, while still being held to state-defined standards and outcomes.
This isn't unique to Pan-Māori organizations. Consider how we've come to see food banks as a normal part of our social support system rather than a sign of systematic failure. The Salvation Army essentially operates as an unofficial branch of social services, but without the funding or authority that comes with being a true state service. We celebrate their work while accepting the privatization of what should arguably be state responsibility.
Even more interesting is how this framework has been adopted across the political spectrum. When the political right talks about reducing state services, they're criticized. But when the same reduction is framed as "empowering communities" or "supporting self-determination," it's often celebrated as progressive.
Take the recent shifts in mental health funding. Moving resources to community providers sounds progressive – it aligns with ideas about local knowledge and cultural competency. But it can also mean shifting state responsibilities to organizations that lack the infrastructure, funding security, or scale to provide systematic solutions.
This creates an accountability gap that serves right-wing interests perfectly: when services fail, the state can blame community providers for poor delivery, while community providers can blame insufficient state funding. Meanwhile, the fundamental question of state responsibility gets lost in the middle.
None of this is to suggest community-led initiatives are wrong. The question isn't whether communities should have authority over their own wellbeing – of course they should. The question is whether that authority should come with proportional resources and genuine autonomy, or whether it's actually a cover for reducing state responsibility while maintaining state control.
What makes this particularly complex in Aotearoa is our Treaty context. Iwi-led initiatives aren't just about service delivery – they're about rangatiratanga, about reclaiming authority that was wrongly taken. But this legitimate aspiration for self-determination can sometimes be co-opted to justify reducing state investment in Māori communities, creating a paradox where tino rangatiratanga becomes a cover for state withdrawal without providing Iwi decision powers over where finding goes.
When we examine successful community-state partnerships, like some Whānau Ora initiatives, we see a different model: genuine devolution of both authority and resources, with communities empowered to define both problems and solutions. But these examples remain exceptions rather than the rule.
The insight here isn't that community-led initiatives are wrong or that state services are always better. It's that we need to be more precise about the difference between genuine community empowerment and the outsourcing of state responsibility. One comes with resources and authority matching the responsibility. The other maintains state control while reducing state investment.
Understanding this distinction might help us have more honest conversations about what we mean when we champion community-led solutions. Are we talking about genuine devolution of power and resources? Or are we accidentally endorsing a right-wing framework of state withdrawal dressed in progressive clothing?
4. The Tax System Paradox: When "Progressive" Taxation Protects Wealth
I was recently asked who I’d vote for. I answered honestly: "With the current tax system, probably the Right—because I don’t think the Left can do what it wants to do within this framework. But if the tax structure changed to raise more revenue, I’d consider voting for the Left." I think our political choices should be grounded on the tax policies each party have, how realistic, accurate and reasonable they are. Everything else rolls down from there.
New Zealand’s tax system presents itself as progressive. Most of governments revenue comes from individual income, business income (28% for most companies and 17.5% for Māori authorities) and goods and services tax. We have marginal income tax rates that increase with earnings, from 10.5% on low incomes (0-$15,600) up to 39% (180,001 and over). The story we tell ourselves is simple: those who earn more contribute more, making the system fair.
But the reality is different. The kinds of income we tax—and the kinds we don’t—reveal a system that isn’t as progressive as it looks. Our tax framework overwhelmingly targets labor income while leaving assets and capital, particularly capital gains and land, largely untouched. This limits what any left-wing government can achieve, because meaningful social investment requires revenue—revenue that our current system simply doesn’t generate.
Take two New Zealanders making $200,000 a year—one as a salaried worker, the other through property investment. The wage earner is taxed at the top income bracket for a portion of their earnings. The property investor, if accumulating capital gains, may pay nothing at all. This is not a loophole—it’s a structural choice. We tax effort comprehensively but tax accumulated wealth lightly, if at all.
GST adds another wrinkle. We often praise New Zealand’s “simple” tax system—one broad-based consumption tax, few exemptions. But simplicity isn’t fairness. Someone earning just enough to cover basic necessities pays 15% GST on almost everything they buy. Meanwhile, someone watching their property appreciate in value pays zero tax on that gain. This makes GST functionally regressive—a flat tax that weighs more heavily on lower-income households.
What’s particularly revealing is what’s missing from our tax system. We once had an inheritance tax, a land tax, and serious debates about a capital gains tax—all of which were abandoned over time. Each of these tools would have shifted some of the tax burden from wage earners to those accumulating passive wealth. Instead, we built a system that taxes work, allowing wealth to grow largely untaxed. A neoliberal trend that the New Zealand Left as not been able to untangle.
This is why my answer about voting makes sense. If the Left wants to fund large-scale public investment—whether in housing, healthcare, or education—it needs significantly more revenue. But under the current system, it simply doesn’t have the fiscal capacity to do so. Unless taxation is restructured to generate that revenue, left-wing governments will always be governing under right-wing fiscal constraints.
Conclusion: Beyond Left and Right—A Call for Policy Honesty
The contradictions we’ve explored—from means-testing to homeownership, from community responsibility to taxation—aren’t random. They stem from a deep confusion between political marketing and policy fundamentals. In New Zealand, we’ve become comfortable labeling policies as "progressive" or "conservative" based on rhetoric, rather than their actual effects.
This isn’t just a theoretical problem—it shapes how we make political decisions. When we mistake market-driven solutions for left-wing victories, we limit our imagination about what’s possible. When we champion community-led initiatives without questioning whether they come with adequate resources, we risk endorsing state withdrawal under the guise of empowerment. When we defend our tax system as fair without acknowledging how it privileges wealth over work, we allow inequality to deepen while thinking we’re addressing it.
None of this means these policies are wrong. Means-testing might be the only politically feasible way to allocate resources. Encouraging homeownership might be a valid goal. Community-driven initiatives can be powerful. But if we want to make real progress, we need to be honest about what we're actually advocating for.
Certainty feels comfortable. It allows us to believe our politics align neatly with our values. But reality is messy, and political labels often obscure more than they clarify. Perhaps the most radical thing we can do is step away from ideological shortcuts and start asking: what do our policies actually achieve?
Because at the end of the day, the real question isn’t whether a policy sounds progressive—it’s whether it actually delivers the outcomes we believe in.
Nat
Good morning, Nat. While I agree 100% that our supposedly progressive tax framework is anything but, I would argue that most left-leaning people are aware of this, and it is largely a matter of political cowardice and inertia that has seen left governments mostly tinker around the edges, rather than try and shift the tax system away from income, labour and spending towards capital and land, the true markers of wealth.
Universalism is indeed fairer and more popular, and crucially removes both the stigma and the sharp cliff edges, but also significantly costs more. Whenever left-leaning governments have proposed more universalism around healthcare, say, the right have derided it as wasteful and expensive, and suggested that it only be focused on “those who need it most”. This has then tended not to transpire.
You rightly point out Super as a universalised exception which is wildly popular. Superannuation is a benefit; it is welfare. It is paid out of current taxation by today’s workers for people too old to work. Yet, most recipients would snarl with disdain if you described it as such. They would say that it’s an entitlement bc they have ‘worked and paid taxes for all their life’ even though that’s not how it is funded! This is because of the ridiculous stigma of language applied to the words ‘benefit’ and ‘welfare’. Until we are more honest as a nation about what people need rather than ‘deserve’, and crucially about how we fund that, real change will prove difficult.
Oh, and loved the housing dilemma framing as well Nat. Is housing a human right or is it a financialised pathway to tax free wealth gain? It’s difficult for it to be both. One idea wants to decrease the housing price and the other wants prices to increase. Tricky.